Better Predictions in Renewable Energy
- ,
- , Modelling

The Problem: Really Bad Predictions
RecentlyΒ Michael LiebreichΒ (founder of Bloomberg New Energy Finance) gave his last βState of Industry Keynoteβ. The link leads to a video and all the 170+ slides: well worth it!
Recently Michael Liebreich βdropped the mikeβ at Bloomberg New Energy Finance
He summarized it in a blog post with the title: βIn Energy and Transportation, Stick it to the Orthodoxyβ and followed up withΒ a 10-point plan to fix energy (and transport) forecasting. He describes how the most authorative organizations in energy and transportation (e.g. the International Energy Agency β IEA β and Energy Information Administration β US EIA) have been demonstrable and colossally wrong in their predictions/scenarios and how we should start to believe in more daring (and hopeful) futures in energy and mobility.
Because my own visualization was first, Iβll use that to show how bad it is for solar panels:
See my blog postΒ for a description of how this graph was made.
And now the IEA has producedΒ a new forecast for 2017. Using the methodology of yearly additions I proposed,Β CarbonBrief shows it is basically same old, same old. They made the analysis for all renewables together (not just solar) but the picture shows the effect is the same as always:
- The starting point for the prediction has moved up (again).
This is something the IEA has no influence over: reality is asserting itself. - The prediction of annual additions stays linear and flat (again).
So the IEA again denies the exponential growth of renewables.
By the way: the IEA is the 900 pound gorilla in this field but the EIA (the US counterpart of the IEA) is just as bad and most other organizations have also severely underestimated the growth of solar.
This is a real problem because it discourages renewable investments and robs us of hope when reality in fact shows us that the investments are working and there is good reason for hope. What explains this negative outlook?
Explanation (1): We are Human with Lots of Biases
All humans (including me!) have biases and they mostly favor the status quo. That is especially true for experts. In order to counter that we should rely more on trends and less on the status quo.
Darwin was ridiculed when he first proposed the theory of evolution
Before we can begin to make predictions we should be able to take a hard look at ourselves and the way we naturally make decisions. Ever since Darwin published βDescent of Manβ, humanity has been coming to terms with the fact that we are just another animal.
We might have better logical reasoning than animals and we seem to be the only one using advanced technology but our desires and decisions are still driven largely byΒ our lizard brain. We are experts atΒ rationalizingour decisions after the fact but our emotions are often a more powerful determinant. So if we are honest we must acknowledge that we are subject to a whole range ofΒ cognitive biasesΒ that skew our ability to make good predictions.
One bias that has been widely noted is thatΒ humans are linear thinkers in a non-linear world. I thinkΒ Ray KurzweilΒ of theΒ Singularity UniversityΒ (of which Eindhoven University of Technology is a partner) has done more than anybody to bring this awareness into our consciousness.
Another very strong bias isΒ confirmation biasΒ [1] which makes us select facts that fit the worldview we already posses.
The sad fact is that when it comes to radical innovation, experts are even less reliable than the average person. Experts are almost by definition focused on the past (because that is where they get their expertise from) and this makes them prone to status quo bias [2] and system justification bias [3]. The result is famously formulated byΒ Arthur C. Clarke in his first law:
When a distinguished but elderly scientist states that something is possible, he is almost certainly right. When he states that something is impossible, he is very probably wrong.
Finally there is the often misunderstood phenomenon ofΒ cognitive dissonance. In βAn Inconvenient Truthβ, Al Gore formulated the influence of this phenomena on certain forecasters and politicians as:
Itβs hard to convince a person if his paycheck depends on not understanding you.
(The quote is originally from Upton Sinclair)
Cognitive dissonance means itβs uncomfortable to hold beliefs that contradict your actions. In a Hollywood movie that means your change your actions but in reality we usually solve this discomfort by changing our beliefs. And very few people are aware of this. So when you have an organization like the IEA that gets its money through consensus and from the status quo, cognitive dissonance theory predicts that IEA members will (unconsciously) embrace beliefs that are in line with the status quo.
Does this mean we should ignore experts? Of course not! First of all, they only have a larger than usual bias in cases ofΒ radical innovationΒ where change is discontinuous. Secondly they have vast knowledge that should not go to waste because of a few biases. We just have to neutralize the biases.
What we could do is embrace the methods put forward by people with a better track record in predicting radical innovation. Iβll explain how to do that when I come to solutions but first I must describe how biases are made worse by our tribes.
Explanation (2): Our Tribes make our Biases Worse
Humans are tribal by nature and our tribal affiliations make us disregard certain scenarios. Three examples:
- Global warming
More than 95-98% of scientists accept that we are in an age of man-made global warming. But in US politics, denying it has become part of the Republican tribal identity withΒ only 24% accepting it, versus 80% of democrats. Another example: if you are a US citizen, you will probably interpret the phrase βAmerica firstβ different thanΒ people in e.g. The Netherlands. - Religion
If you are religious, chances are you have the same religion as your parents and think that other religions have a weaker grasp of the truth. However, people in other religions think so too. If I would use the scientific method to analyze this problem I would say the simplest explanation that makes sense for all religions is that religious teachings are not βtrueβ in the scientific sense but rather a set of values and norms that we learn from the tribe we grow up in. - Empathy for animals
If we ever reachΒ the age of empathyΒ and become anΒ empathic civilization, I think itβs plausible that we will one day extend our empathy to more than just humans. Once it was considered uncivil to discuss the idea that slaves or women had rights. Now the opposite is true. My personal estimate is that there will come a time when we will treat the suffering of pets and pigs with equal compassion and considerΒ industrial farming one of the worst crimes in history.
A visualization of how the Overton Window limits discussion to what is acceptable
The point Iβm making is that the tribe we live in, limits the window of discourse we can have. In his keynote and blog post, Liebreich introduces this phenomena as the βOverton windowβ (see illustration) and poses that this makes it difficult to make good predictions in energy and mobility.
This is also true for tribes of experts. We already mentioned linear thinking, confirmation bias, status quo bias and system justification bias but all these are exacerbated by theΒ groupthink,Β information biasΒ andΒ consensus seekingthat occur when experts have to work in groups [4]. When that happens it is a safe bet that the resulting predictions will be even more orthodox, than the ones the experts would make on their own.
So it is actually not hard to explain why groups of experts are consistently much too conservative and orthodox and how they have a blind spot for radical innovations. The good news is that itβs also not very hard to explain what we have to do about it. Letβs turn to solutions!
The Solution: How to make Better Predictions of Radical Innovation
I propose five criteria that Iβve visualized in the picture you saw in the introduction:
If you have read so far I thank you dear reader. But fair warning: the rest of this post is meant for people who work with energy models professionally. Others might find it too detailed but I wanted to put it out there.
1) Open Source Modelling: the Scientific Method for the 21stΒ Century
Sunlight is the best disinfectant. Allow others outside your tribe to falsify your model or play with the assumptions to get different results. Without this, bias can go unchecked.
The scientific method might have some antidotes against the discussed biases because it tries to be independent (as much as possible) from the scientist making the prediction. ToΒ quote Richard Feynman:
The first principle [of science] is that you must not fool yourself
and you are the easiest person to fool.
In order to avoid fooling him or herself, a scientist is required to open up himself to criticism as much as possible. Science is based onΒ falsifiability: your findings are only taken seriously if they can beΒ disproven. When you make your claims easier to disprove, you are taken more seriously. Or more popularly formulated: βIn God we trust, all others bring data.β
When J.B.S. Haldane was asked how evolution theory could be falsified he famously answered: βFossil rabbits in the Precambrianβ: anybody digging through rocks finds rabbit bones everywhere, but if they where found in very old rocks β from before there where supposed to be mammals β this would immediately turn the theory of evolution on its head. (In case youβre wondering: nope.)
Now for obvious reasons, predictions about the future are harder to disprove than predictions about the past. But what we can do is maximize transparency so that each and every piece of data, every equation, every step leading up to your prediction can be scrutinized by others.
One way to implement this is through peer review. Peer reviewing means that before publication, your article is read and critiqued in detail by other scientists that are knowledgeable in your area. Β It is only printed once you have addressed al criticism. However, you might understand how peer review could also introduce the type of bias towards orthodoxy that we discussed previously. It is well known that professors can sometimes stymie change until they retire. For this reason science is sometimes said to progress one funeral at a time.
But we donβt need to succumb to orthodoxy if we want to keep the most important part of peer review. The essence of peer review is falsifiability: opening yourself up to detailed criticism by other knowledgeable individuals. For radical innovation these knowledgeable individuals should include voices from outside the orthodoxy. E.g. students, scientists (from areas where the Overton window is different) and investigative journalists.
The solution seems obvious to me. Your raw data, your assumptions and your model should be publicly available. Preferably in an easy to download format on the web. E.g. a github repository for code and a csv file for data.
In this respect the current state of energy predictions is miserable. Models like the WEM (World Economic Model) of the IEA (International Energy Agency) are not publicly available, let alone easy to download in the form of a github repository. And this also holds true for most other models. One reason is that experts donβt like to make themselves vulnerable unless they are forced to. An even more important reason that these predictions are increasingly intellectual property of consultancy firms that make money from using a black box. The result is that anybody can choose the black box that delivers the results he or she likes and our problems are worse than ever.
If we are even halfway serious about addressing the aforementioned biases, this secrecy is anathema.
The first litmus test: βAre model and data downloadable
so anybody can verify and reproduce the results?β
If the answer is βnoβ I propose we exclude the predictions of the model as the basis for serious decision making. And since the IEA word economic model is closed I propose we open it up.
And the first thing I would do if I got my hands on it would be to see if I could make it reproduce past developments in renewable energy more accurately. I expect it will not able to match past developments which would basically make it a falsified model.
2) Learning Curves as Constants
Take change as a constant instead of a fluke. Accept it unless you can prove it will slow down. Reverse the burden of evidence away from the status quo.
I already mentioned Ray Kurzweil. What he discovered is that often he had ideas for inventions that where ahead of their time: synthesizers, optical character recognition, speech recognition, artificial intelligence, etc. They relied on technology that was not there yet. So he thought: if I could predict how fast supporting technologies like computers will progress I can estimate when my invention should be ready for market. He started doing that with a lot of success and it is now used by institutes like the Singularity University. I propose we use that approach in renewable energy too.
If you simplify the approach to the utmost essential, you look at how a technology progresses over time and you extrapolate the past into the future. This is commonly called the learning curve approach. This goes further than how economists have used learning curves in the past. In the past it was used narrowly for production processes in a factory that showed a tendency to lower costs with increasing economies of scale. The approach we are talking about here goes much further. It assumes that learning curves about technologies can hold over the total of human efforts. So this includes not only factory floors but also university researchers, venture capitalists and inventors. One of the examples that still blows me away is that Mooreβs Law actually holds over multiple technologies.
Mooreβs lawΒ is not only true for ICs but also for information technologies that came before it.
If this trend holds (and there is every indication it is doing just that), the computing that $1000 can buy will increase from the raw brain power of a not so smart mouse in 2017 to the brain power of all human brains put together in 2050. Now a machine with loads of brain power is not automatically smart, but when combined with advances in visual systems and pattern recognition I find it hard to tell people with a straight face that we will be driving cars ourselves in the future.
Solar panels are an equivalent development in the renewable energy domain:
And actually this is true for most energy technologies as the nextΒ picture of the European CommissionΒ shows (picture is outdated β from 2003 β but gives a nice overview):
If you see this you think everything is getting cheaper rapidly. But there are two reasons renewables benefit from this learning much more than fossil fuels:
- Renewables donβt use fuel. So once youβve build your solar or wind farm, the energy is essentially free. With a gas fired power plant your fuel is actually much costlier than building your powerplant (over the lifetime of the plant) so the learning curve is of limited influence.
- Renewables are still small. The curves in the picture show that increasing the volume decreases the price. But if you look at mature technologies that hardly grow anymore, the effect of learning is minimal. But with e.g. solar, off-shore wind and batteries there is an enormous amount of price reducing learning in store.
So learning curves is what enables renewable generation to blow fossil fuels right out of the water. But what about storage for when the wind doesnβt blow and the sun doesnβt shine? For those cases thereβs batteries and hereΒ a new graph from Schmidt et al in NatureΒ that is illuminating:
So in terms of storage that enables solar and wind to produce base load and that makes electric vehicles cheaper learning curves are equally or more aggressive.
Now this does not end understanding. E.g. I do a lot of research into the raw materials that go into lithium batteries and electric drivetrains so I can double check the learning curves. And I often end up making them a little less aggressive in the long term just to be sure. But they are still my starting point. Ignoring them would be taking the whole shebang in biases on board. So:
The second litmus test: βAre all the relevant technologies modelled as individual learning curves and are their formulas and influence verifiable?β
Now I donβt know how well the IEA model scores here (since itβs secret) but indirectly Iβve heard it whispered that in the WEM, the learning curves of production are modeled but storage is very expensive, which impedes solar and wind. My guess is that demand-response, short term storage (batteries) and long term storage (e.g. electrolysis and fuel cells) have been modeled inadequately.
3) Endogenous Feedback Loops
Change should be able to speed up change. E.g. lower PV price => higher PV sales.
When I started into this field ten years or so ago I came upon an article using learning curves and feedback loops for solar energy. I noticed that the growth per year in the article was never more than 27%. So I called the researcher and asked: βWhy?β He basically told me that going any higher would make the article an object of ridicule. But thatβs not a good reason! Thatβs a whole list of aforementioned biases at work! Since then the PV market has grown with on average 43% so the overall growth has been several times higher than the article predicted. That also means more price reduction (using the learning curve) so that itβs now less than half of what the article predicted. And this article was so positive that it was considered almost unseriousβ¦
The next graph neatly visualizes that changeΒ can occur relatively rapidly:
And multiple applications have noted that endogenous feedback loops lead to a more renewable friendly response. A review of 25 well known models concludes that the impact is significant [5]. So:
The third litmus test: βAre the important learning curves and adoption rates connected through feedback loops?β
4) Bottom-up modelling
With agent-based modelling the system emerges from assumptions and interactions. Itβs not imposed. Unfortunately almost all models are still equilibrium models that produce unrealistic results, especially when the topic is radical innovation.
Making an open source model using learning curves is relatively easy and will overcome most biases. Adding feedback loops is somewhat more complex and requires some macros in excel or good system dynamics software. But if you really want to model radical change you have to take the next step and that means making full use of computers.
Letβs start with how NOT to do it. Economics has a track record to rival that of the IEA on solar panels. In my humble opinion, people outside of economics would be horrified if they knew how unrealistic most economic models are. The dominant models are called equilibrium models (or CGE for Computed Generalized Equilibrium or DSGE for Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium). Fagiolo et al [6] document how these DSGE models became the consensus in 2008. Economists triumphantly exclaimed that monetary policy was finally becoming science. And then, a few months later, the financial crisis unexpectedly hit [7]β[9].
Equilibrium models are based on βthe holy trinity of rationality, selfishness, and equilibriumβ [10]. They assumeΒ βrationalβ actorsΒ that can be represented by a couple of βrepresentativeβ aggregated agents[6].Β Such βrationalβ actors only strive for utility maximization. They immediately know the utility of every product and price on the market. They are impervious to status, strategizing, populism, idealism, tribalism, hearsay or marketing. They donβt empathize with future generations because the discount rate tells that a life in 2100 is worth only worth 1/100thΒ of life today. They cannot use their wealth to help people in other countries because Negishi welfare weights forbid it. Furthermore the actors function inΒ βidealβ markets.Β This means, among other things, no bankers with perverse incentives, no lobbyists, no political games, no idealists, no monopolistic tendencies, no network effects, no incumbent resistance to change, et cetera.
If you think this sounds completely unrealistic you are in good company: most psychologists, sociologists, political scientists, marketers and entrepreneurs agree with you [11]. They accuse economists of βa steadfast refusal to face factsβ [12]. Itβs all due to a well-meant attempt to capture our civilization in a few mathematical equations. But itβs not working. To quote Ackerman [13]: βThe mathematical dead end reached by general equilibrium analysis is not due to obscure or esoteric aspects of the model, but rather arises from intentional design features β¦ Modification of economic theory β¦ will require a new model of consumer choice, nonlinear analyses of social interactions, and recognition of the central role of institutional and social constraintsβ. Nobel laureate Paul Krugman adds [14]: βAs I see it, the economics profession went astray because economists, as a group, mistook beauty, clad in impressive-looking mathematics, for truth. β¦ Economists need to abandon the neat but wrong solution of assuming that everyone is rational and markets work perfectly. The vision that emerges as the profession rethinks its foundations may not be all that clear; it certainly wonβt be neat; but we can hope that it will have the virtue of being at least partly right.β
If you think this had nothing to do with energy I have more bad news for you. Currently most energy models are largely equilibrium models. E.g. the World Energy Model (used by the IEA for its influential βEnergy Outlookβ series), POLES (used by Enerdata) and PRIMES (used by the European Commission) [15]. Stanton et al [16] also review the following integrated assessment models using CGE: JAM; IGEM; IGSM/EPPA (MIT); SMG; WORLDSCAN (CPB); ABARE-GTEM; G-CUBED; MS-MRT; AIM; IMACLIM-R; WIAGEM; MiniCAM and GIM.
But there is hope! From biology and ecology we have learned how real world systems like our society work. We call them complex adaptive systems now. The bad news is that such systems are confusing to our primate brain. (Due to non-linearity, feedback, time delays and interdependencies [18]. We see that in empirical studies [19]β[23].) The good news is that we can understand them with the help of a computer if we use agent-based models (ABM) [17], [24], [25]. Some are so enthusiastic that they call it βa third way of doing scienceβ and I agree [26], [27].
Three simulation methods that improve equilibrium models [17]
ABM is a young discipline with the first computer models in the 80βs and 90βs but ABM is now a fast growing field [28], [29] and the preferred modelling method complex adaptive socio-technical systems [30], [31]. Itβs widely used in health [32], organizational science [33]; emergency response [34]; land use [35], [36]; manufacturing [37]; ecosystem management [38]; and marketing [39], [40]. In economics there is now a 900 page handbook of agent-based computational economics [41] (although most students are still taught the old equilibrium models).
Energy systems are ideal for ABM [42]β[45]. Very active fields are smart grids [46]β[48], electricity markets [49]β[51], distributed generation [52] and transportation [53]β[56]. And if you look at models that aim to manage the transition to renewable energy, half is already an ABM [57].
The fourth litmus test: does the model use bottom-up agent-based modelling?
5) Realistic Infrastructure
Our behavior is also determined by our environment. A model should contain buildings, grids etc.
Letβs take electric vehicle adoption as an example. Batteries need to be cheap enough before people will buy electric vehicles, that is obvious and addressed by requirements 2 (use learning curves) and 3 (endogenous feedback loops). Maybe you even model people that buy electric vehicles, thereby addressing my requirement 4 (bottom-up agent-based modelling).
But even then there will be barriers to adoption. If we take the case of solar panels you must have a roof to put them on if you want to buy them for your house. So space is an important requirement. If your neighbor already has them, you might speak to him or her about it which increases your chance to buy them so your environment is important. And if a country gets a lot of solar panels is might have to think of how to deal with peaks on the electricity grid. So the grid is also important.
I think the best way to deal with this is to model the geographic infrastructure explicitly. Itβs often called GIS data for geographical information system. Fortunately more and more of this type of information is available as open source data. E.g. Google maps uses such data. The advantage of using GIS data is not only that is forces you to deal with limitations in infrastructure. It also enables coupling different systems based on their location. You can download it and use it in your agent-based model using state-of-the-art tools likeΒ GAMA.
Example of a neighborhood with different layers in one of my models
Now Iβm not claiming that every good model should use GIS data. But it really helps you to integrate different subsystems based on their spatial coordinates. Furthermore, using real world data like this forces you to deal with reality instead of preconceived notions and thus really helps to overcome biases: itβs simply very hard to model your biases into such a model.
Fifth litmus test: does the model use realistic spatial relationships and infrastructural constraints.
Wow, you really made it till here? Congratulations! I would love to hear your critique or feedback. And I hope there are some people that will in some ways improve an energy model because he or she read this. Hereβs to hoping!
References
[1]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β R. Nickerson, βConfirmation bias: a ubiquitous phenomenon in many guises,βΒ Rev. Gen. Psychol., vol. 2, no. 2, pp. 175β220, 1998.
[2]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β W. Samuelson and R. Zeckhauser, βStatus quo bias in decision making,βΒ J. Risk Uncertain., vol. 1, no. 1, pp. 7β59, Mar. 1988.
[3]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β J. T. Jost, M. R. Banaji, and B. A. Nosek, βA Decade of System Justification Theory: Accumulated Evidence of Conscious and Unconscious Bolstering of the Status Quo,βΒ Polit. Psychol., vol. 25, no. 6, pp. 881β919, Dec. 2004.
[4]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β T. Postmes, R. Spears, and S. Cihangir, βQuality of decision making and group norms.,βΒ J. Pers. Soc. Psychol., vol. 80, no. 6, pp. 918β930, 2001.
[5]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β K. Gillingham, R. G. Newell, and W. A. Pizer, βModeling endogenous technological change for climate policy analysis,βΒ Energy Econ., vol. 30, no. 6, pp. 2734β2753, Nov. 2008.
[6]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β G. Fagiolo and A. Roventini, βMacroeconomic policy in dsge and agent-based models redux: New developments and challenges ahead,β 2016.
[7]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β F. S. Mishkin, βWill Monetary Policy Become More of a Science?,β inΒ The Science and Practice of Monetary Policy Today, Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg, 2010, pp. 81β103.
[8]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β M. Goodfriend, βHow the World Achieved Consensus on Monetary Policy,βΒ J. Econ. Perspect., vol. 21, no. 4, pp. 47β68, 2007.
[9]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β Β J. GalΓ and M. Gertler, βMacroeconomic modeling for monetary policy evaluation,βΒ J. Econ. Perspect., vol. 21, no. 4, pp. 25β45, 2007.
[10]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β D. Colander, R. Holt, and B. R. Jr, βThe changing face of mainstream economics,βΒ Rev. Polit. Econ., vol. 16, no. 4, pp. 485β499, Oct. 2004.
[11]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β V. Mosini,Β Equilibrium in Economics: Scope and Limits. Routledge, 2008.
[12]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β C. A. E. Goodhart, βThe Continuing Muddles of Monetary Theory: A Steadfast Refusal to Face Facts,βΒ Economica, vol. 76, no. s1, pp. 821β830, 2009.
[13]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β F. Ackerman, βStill dead after all these years: interpreting the failure of general equilibrium theory,βΒ J. Econ. Methodol., vol. 9, no. 2, pp. 119β139, 2002.
[14]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β P. Krugman, βHow Did Economists Get It So Wrong?,βΒ The New York Times, 02-Sep-2009.
[15]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β A. Herbst, F. Toro, F. Reitze, and E. Jochem, βIntroduction to energy systems modelling,βΒ Swiss J. Econ. Stat., vol. 148, no. 2, pp. 111β135, 2012.
[16]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β E. A. Stanton, F. Ackerman, and S. Kartha, βInside the integrated assessment models: Four issues in climate economics,βΒ Clim. Dev., vol. 1, no. 2, p. 166, Jul. 2009.
[17]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β A. Borshchev,Β The Big Book of Simulation Modeling: Multimethod Modeling with Anylogic 6. Lisle, IL: AnyLogic North America, 2013.
[18]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β J. D. Sterman, βLearning in and about complex systems,βΒ Syst. Dyn. Rev., vol. 10, no. 2β3, pp. 291β330, Jun. 1994.
[19]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β P. W. B. Atkins, R. E. Wood, and P. J. Rutgers, βThe effects of feedback format on dynamic decision making,βΒ Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process., vol. 88, no. 2, pp. 587β604, Jul. 2002.
[20]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β B. Brehmer, βDynamic decision making: Human control of complex systems,βΒ Acta Psychol. (Amst.), vol. 81, no. 3, pp. 211β241, Dec. 1992.
[21]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β E. Diehl and J. D. Sterman, βEffects of Feedback Complexity on Dynamic Decision Making,βΒ Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process., vol. 62, no. 2, pp. 198β215, May 1995.
[22]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β D. N. Kleinmuntz, βInformation processing and misperceptions of the implications of feedback in dynamic decision making,βΒ Syst. Dyn. Rev., vol. 9, no. 3, pp. 223β237, Sep. 1993.
[23]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β J. D. Sterman, βModeling Managerial Behavior: Misperceptions of Feedback in a Dynamic Decision Making Experiment,βΒ Manag. Sci., vol. 35, no. 3, pp. 321β339, Mar. 1989.
[24]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β M. A. Bedau, βWeak Emergence,βΒ NoΓ»s, vol. 31, pp. 375β399, Jan. 1997.
[25]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β J. Epstein and R. Axtell,Β Growing Artificial Societies: Social Science From the Bottom Up (Complex Adaptive Systems). Brookings Institution PressΒ MIT Press, 1996.
[26]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β R. Axelrod, βAdvancing the Art of Simulation in the Social Sciences,β inΒ Simulating Social Phenomena, D. R. Conte, P. D. R. Hegselmann, and P. D. P. Terna, Eds. Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 1997, pp. 21β40.
[27]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β J. Epstein, βAgent-Based Computational Models And GenerativeΒ Social Science,βΒ Gener. Soc. Sci. Stud. Agent-Based Comput. Model., p. 4, 2006.
[28]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β E. Bonabeau, βAgent-based modeling: Methods and techniques for simulating human systems,βΒ Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci., vol. 99, no. suppl 3, pp. 7280β7287, May 2002.
[29]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β S. de Marchi and S. E. Page, βAgent-Based Models,βΒ Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci., vol. 17, no. 1, pp. 1β20, 2014.
[30]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β K. H. Van Dam, βCapturing socio-technical systems with agent-based modelling,β PhD Thesis, TU Delft, Delft University of Technology, 2009.
[31]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β K. H. van Dam, I. Nikolic, and Z. Lukszo,Β Agent-Based Modelling of Socio-Technical Systems. Springer Publishing Company, Incorporated, 2014.
[32]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β R. Hilscher, βReview of A Spatial Agent-Based Simulation Modeling in Public Health: Design, Implementation, and Applications for Malaria Epidemiology (Wiley Series in Modeling and Simulation),β 13-Jan-2017. [Online]. Available:Β http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/20/1/reviews/2.html. [Accessed: 01-Apr-2017].
[33]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β G. Fioretti, βAgent-Based Simulation Models in Organization Science,βΒ Organ. Res. Methods, vol. 16, no. 2, pp. 227β242, Apr. 2013.
[34]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β G. I. Hawe, G. Coates, D. T. Wilson, and R. S. Crouch, βAgent-based simulation for large-scale emergency response: A survey of usage and implementation,βΒ ACM Comput. Surv., vol. 45, no. 1, pp. 1β51, Nov. 2012.
[35]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β R. B. Matthews, N. G. Gilbert, A. Roach, J. G. Polhill, and N. M. Gotts, βAgent-based land-use models: a review of applications,βΒ Landsc. Ecol., vol. 22, no. 10, pp. 1447β1459, Dec. 2007.
[36]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β D. C. Parker, S. M. Manson, M. A. Janssen, M. J. Hoffmann, and P. Deadman, βMulti-Agent Systems for the Simulation of Land-Use and Land-Cover Change: A Review,βΒ Ann. Assoc. Am. Geogr., vol. 93, no. 2, pp. 314β337, Jun. 2003.
[37]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β W. Shen, Q. Hao, H. J. Yoon, and D. H. Norrie, βApplications of agent-based systems in intelligent manufacturing: An updated review,βΒ Adv. Eng. Inform., vol. 20, no. 4, pp. 415β431, Oct. 2006.
[38]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β F. Bousquet and C. Le Page, βMulti-agent simulations and ecosystem management: a review,βΒ Ecol. Model., vol. 176, no. 3β4, pp. 313β332, Sep. 2004.
[39]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β G. P. Richardson and P. Otto, βApplications of system dynamics in marketing: Editorial,βΒ J. Bus. Res., vol. 61, no. 11, pp. 1099β1101, Nov. 2008.
[40]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β A. Negahban and L. Yilmaz, βAgent-based simulation applications in marketing research: an integrated review,βΒ J. Simul., vol. 8, no. 2, pp. 129β142, May 2014.
[41]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β L. Tesfatsion and K. L. Judd, Eds.,Β Handbook of computational economics volume 2: Agent-based computational economics. Amsterdam Boston: Elsevier, 2006.
[42]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β C. S. E. Bale, L. Varga, and T. J. Foxon, βEnergy and complexity: New ways forward,βΒ Appl. Energy, vol. 138, pp. 150β159, Jan. 2015.
[43]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β T. Ma and Y. Nakamori, βModeling technological change in energy systems β From optimization to agent-based modeling,βΒ Energy, vol. 34, no. 7, pp. 873β879, 2009.
[44]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β E. j. l. Chappin and G. p. j. Dijkema, βAgent-based modelling of energy infrastructure transitions,βΒ Int. J. Crit. Infrastruct., vol. 6, no. 2, pp. 106β130, Jan. 2010.
[45]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β V. Rai and A. D. Henry, βAgent-based modelling of consumer energy choices,βΒ Nat. Clim. Change, vol. 6, no. 6, pp. 556β562, Jun. 2016.
[46]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β P. Ringler, D. Keles, and W. Fichtner, βAgent-based modelling and simulation of smart electricity grids and markets β A literature review,βΒ Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev., vol. 57, pp. 205β215, May 2016.
[47]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β R. Roche, B. Blunier, A. Miraoui, V. Hilaire, and A. Koukam, βMulti-agent systems for grid energy management: A short review,β inΒ IECON 2010 β 36th Annual Conference on IEEE Industrial Electronics Society, 2010, pp. 3341β3346.
[48]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β P. VrbaΒ et al., βA Review of Agent and Service-Oriented Concepts Applied to Intelligent Energy Systems,βΒ IEEE Trans. Ind. Inform., vol. 10, no. 3, pp. 1890β1903, Aug. 2014.
[49]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β F. SensfuΓ, M. Ragwitz, M. Genoese, and D. MΓΆst, βAgent-based simulation of electricity markets: a literature review,β Working paper sustainability and innovation, 2007.
[50]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β R. Marks, βChapter 27 Market Design Using Agent-Based Models,β inΒ Handbook of Computational Economics, vol. 2, L. T. and K. L. Judd, Ed. Elsevier, 2006, pp. 1339β1380.
[51]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β J. Babic and V. Podobnik, βA review of agent-based modelling of electricity markets in future energy eco-systems,β inΒ 2016 International Multidisciplinary Conference on Computer and Energy Science (SpliTech), 2016, pp. 1β9.
[52]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β J. G. Veneman, M. A. Oey, L. J. Kortmann, F. M. Brazier, and L. J. de Vries, βA Review of Agent-based Models for Forecasting the Deployment of Distributed Generation in Energy Systems,β inΒ Proceedings of the 2011 Grand Challenges on Modeling and Simulation Conference, Vista, CA, 2011, pp. 16β21.
[53]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β B. Chen and H. H. Cheng, βA Review of the Applications of Agent Technology in Traffic and Transportation Systems,βΒ IEEE Trans. Intell. Transp. Syst., vol. 11, no. 2, pp. 485β497, Jun. 2010.
[54]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β A. L. C. Bazzan and F. KlΓΌgl, βA review on agent-based technology for traffic and transportation,βΒ Knowl. Eng. Rev., vol. 29, no. 03, pp. 375β403, Jun. 2014.
[55]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β US Department of Transportation, βA Primer for Agent-Based Simulation and Modeling in Transportation Applications.β [Online]. Available:Β https://www.fhwa.dot.gov/advancedresearch/pubs/13054/13054.pdf. [Accessed: 13-Apr-2016].
[56]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β N. Ronald, R. Thompson, and S. Winter, βSimulating Demand-responsive Transportation: A Review of Agent-based Approaches,βΒ Transp. Rev., vol. 35, no. 4, pp. 404β421, Jul. 2015.
[57]Β Β Β Β Β Β Β F. G. N. Li, E. Trutnevyte, and N. Strachan, βA review of socio-technical energy transition (STET) models,βΒ Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change, vol. 100, pp. 290β305, Nov. 2015.